as-a-service
Service charge
parallax background

Reinventing retirement

How to reinvent pension systems before demographics demolish them

August 12, 2025

7 min read

August 12, 2025

7 min read

Photo: Dreamstime.

The arithmetic of ageing is unforgiving. In 2020 there were, on average, 3.4 working-age people to support the retirement of every person 65 and older across Europe. By 2050, that number is projected to dwindle to just two. Japan has already reached this precipice. More than 35 other countries will join it within a generation. Politicians worldwide however persist in treating pension reform as an electoral third rail, preferring to tinker at the margins rather than confront the fundamental mismatch between 20th-century systems and 21st-century demographics.

The conventional wisdom suggests only one escape route: raise the retirement age. But this remedy, while mathematically sound, is politically toxic.

France’s recent protests over proposed pension reforms demonstrate the explosive nature of such changes. Stabilising the old-age dependency ratio between 2015 and 2050 would require an increase in retirement age of a stunning 8.4 years on average across OECD countries—a politically impossible leap that far exceeds projected increases in longevity.

Fortunately, demography need not be destiny. A growing number of countries are pioneering alternatives that sidestep the retirement-age bottleneck whilst ensuring system sustainability. The question is not whether pension systems must change, but whether they will evolve intelligently or collapse chaotically.

The Swedish solution: Automatic pilot

Sweden offers perhaps the most elegant escape from the demographic trap. Its pension reform, implemented in the late 1990s, shifted to a system of notional accounts that rendered the system fair, transparent, and sustainable whilst enjoying broad political consensus. Rather than politicians deciding benefit levels through fraught negotiations, the system automatically adjusts based on demographic and economic realities.

Each worker’s payroll tax is credited to an individual notional account, with ‘earnings’ based on Sweden’s per capita wage growth. Beginning at age 61, workers can retire, and the government calculates an annuity based on life expectancy. The beauty lies in its automaticity: as life expectancy increases, benefits adjust downward unless workers choose to retire later. No parliamentary battles required.

The results are impressive. More than two decades later, the reform has rendered the system fiscally sustainable and politically stable. More crucially, it has shifted the political discourse. Rather than debating whether to cut benefits or raise taxes, Swedes discuss how to optimise their retirement timing—a far more palatable conversation.

The automaticity advantage

Sweden’s success has inspired a broader movement towards automatic adjustment mechanisms (AAMs). Seven countries now adjust the statutory retirement age according to changes in life expectancy (Denmark, Estonia, Finland, Greece, Italy, Netherlands and Portugal), whilst six others adjust pensions in relation to changes in life expectancy, the size of the active population, or GDP.

These mechanisms remove pension reform from the political arena, replacing emotional debates with technical adjustments. The political risk of inaction or wrong action on pension reform is greatly reduced when parameters adjust automatically based on objective criteria rather than electoral calculations.

Germany’s pension system exemplifies this approach. Its ‘pension brake’ automatically reduces benefit growth when the ratio of pensioners to contributors deteriorates. Canada’s system features a balancing mechanism that adjusts both benefits and contributions to maintain long-term equilibrium. These countries have discovered that voters more readily accept gradual, predictable adjustments than dramatic, politically-driven reforms.

The contribution revolution

Whilst automatic adjustments address the sustainability challenge, they do little to solve the adequacy crisis facing younger workers. New UK analysis shows that retirees in 2050 are on course to be poorer than today’s pensioners if nothing changes. The collapse of defined-benefit schemes and sluggish voluntary savings rates mean millions face impoverished retirements.

Britain’s automatic enrolment programme, launched in 2012, offers a template for boosting private savings without coercion. Some 88 per cent of eligible employees are now saving, up from 55 per cent when the programme was launched. The secret lies in behavioural economics: making saving the default option whilst allowing workers to opt out. Most simply never bother to leave.

However, even Britain’s success highlights the scale of the challenge. The UK’s recent Pensions Review proposes extending minimum employer contributions to almost all employees and suggests reforms that could generate around 11 billion UK pounds in additional annual savings.

Countries serious about pension adequacy must embrace far more aggressive auto-enrolment, potentially reaching Australian levels where mandatory contributions approach 12 per cent of wages.

The means-testing migration

For countries facing acute demographic pressure, means-testing offers another avenue. Means-tested pension systems have two built-in automatic devices: a fiscal stabilisation device and a redistributive device that automatically adapt pension payments to changing demographic trends.

Australia pioneered this approach with its means-tested Age Pension alongside mandatory superannuation. The system automatically targets support towards those who need it most whilst encouraging private savings among the better-off. Under more pronounced population ageing scenarios, the automatic mechanism becomes more effective, requiring more progressive means testing rules.

Critics argue that means-testing discourages savings by penalising thrift. Yet research suggests the opposite: knowing that a safety net exists allows people to take greater investment risks with their private savings, potentially boosting long-term returns.

An intriguing hybrid has emerged in the form of collective defined contribution (CDC) schemes. These pool investment risks across groups whilst maintaining individual accounts. The Netherlands’ pension funds have long operated similar arrangements, achieving superior returns through professional management and risk-sharing whilst maintaining transparency.

Their advantage lies in combining the security of collective investment with the accountability of individual accounts. Workers benefit from professional fund management without bearing sole responsibility for investment decisions.

The labour market lever

No pension reform cannot succeed in isolation from labour market policy. Closing gender gaps in labour force participation, promoting access to high-quality, affordable childcare, and encouraging older workers to keep working are essential complements to pension system changes.

The potential gains are substantial. Only 50 per cent of women participate in the labour force globally, compared with 80 percent of men. Countries that boost female participation whilst encouraging later retirement can dramatically improve their dependency ratios without touching pension parameters.

France’s recent labour market reforms, alongside its controversial pension changes, recognise this connection. Successful pension reform requires viewing retirement security as part of a broader economic strategy, not an isolated social programme.

The technology transformation

Technology offers additional levers for pension innovation. Blockchain could enable portable pension accounts that follow workers across jobs and borders. Artificial intelligence could provide personalised retirement planning advice at scale. Robo-advisors are already democratising investment management for pension savers.

More fundamentally, technology may reshape the nature of retirement itself. As remote work extends working lives and gig economies proliferate, the binary transition from work to retirement may give way to more gradual, flexible arrangements.

Pension systems designed around traditional employment patterns will need updating for this new reality.

The political imperative

The greatest obstacle to pension reform remains political rather than technical. Reform success is sometimes attributed to the political skillfulness of one or a few individuals, but Sweden’s experience suggests a deeper lesson: successful reform requires creating more winners than losers.

When comparing the net effect of the new and old Swedish systems, contributions of the working generation were reduced by more than their expected benefits. Young workers supported reform because they gained more than they lost. Politicians seeking pension reform must craft similar coalitions.

The window for intelligent reform is narrowing. Each year of delay makes adjustment more painful as demographic pressures intensify. Countries that act now can implement gradual changes; those that wait will face crisis-driven reforms that please no one.

Beyond the age obsession

The fixation on retirement age reflects a failure of imagination. Pension systems face multiple challenges: sustainability, adequacy, equity, and political feasibility. Raising retirement age addresses only one of these, whilst exacerbating others.

The countries leading pension innovation understand that comprehensive reform requires multiple tools: automatic adjustment mechanisms for sustainability, enhanced auto-enrolment for adequacy, means-testing for equity, and careful political management for feasibility. No single reform will suffice; successful countries are implementing comprehensive packages.

The demographic transition is unstoppable, but pension crisis is not inevitable. Sweden, Australia, Denmark, and others have demonstrated that intelligent reform can preserve retirement security whilst maintaining fiscal sustainability. The question is whether other countries will learn from these examples or persist with systems designed for a world that no longer exists.

The arithmetic of ageing is indeed unforgiving. But with sufficient political will and policy innovation, it need not be insurmountable. The pension systems of the future will look radically different from those of the past—the only question is whether the transformation will be planned or forced by crisis.

Wise governments will choose the former whilst they still can.

Photo: Dreamstime.

Share